Authors: Professor Michael Hardt,Antonio Negri
Tags: #Philosophy, #Political, #Political Science, #General, #American Government
aligned perspective gave a first glimpse ofa new and generalized
desire.
The question what to do after liberation so as not to fall under
the domination ofone camp or the other remained unanswered.
What were clear and full of potential, by contrast, were the subjectiv-
ities that pushed beyond modernity. The utopian image ofthe
Soviet and Chinese revolutions as alternatives for development
vanished when those revolutions could no longer go forward, or
rather when they failed to find a way to go beyond modernity.
The U.S. model ofdevelopment appeared equally closed, since
throughout the postwar period the United States presented itself
more as the police force of the old imperialisms than the agent of
a new hope. The struggle ofsubaltern populations for their liberation
remained an explosive and uncontainable mixture. By the end of
the 1960s the liberation struggles, whose influence had come to be
felt in every interstice of world space, assumed a force, a mobility,
and a plasticity ofform that drove the project ofcapitalist moderniza-
tion (in both its liberal and its socialist guises) out into an open sea,
where it lost its bearings. Behind the fac¸ade ofthe bipolar U.S.-
Soviet divide they could discern a single disciplinary model, and
against this model the enormous movements struggled, in forms
that were more or less ambiguous, more or less mystified, but
nonetheless real. This enormous new subjectivity alluded to and
made necessary a paradigm shift.
The inadequacy ofthe theory and practice ofmodern sover-
eignty became evident at this point. By the 1960s and 1970s, even
though the model ofdisciplinary modernization had been imposed
D I S C I P L I N A R Y G O V E R N A B I L I T Y
251
across the world, even though the welfarist policies set in motion by
the dominant countries had become unstoppable and were naively
championed by leaders in the subordinated countries, and even
in this new world ofcommunicative media and networks, the
mechanisms ofmodern sovereignty were no longer sufficient to
rule the new subjectivities. We should point out here that as the
paradigm of modern sovereignty lost its effectiveness, so too the
classical theories ofimperialism and anti-imperialism lost whatever
explanatory powers they had. In general, when these theories con-
ceived the surpassing ofimperialism, they saw it as a process that
would be in perfect continuity with the paradigm of modernization
and modern sovereignty. What happened, however, was exactly
the opposite. Massified subjectivities, populations, oppressed classes,
in the very moment when they entered the processes ofmoderniza-
tion, began to transform them and go beyond them. The struggles
for liberation, in the very moment when they were situated and
subordinated in the world market, recognized insufficient and tragic
keystone ofmodern sovereignty. Exploitation and domination
could no longer be imposed in their modern forms. As these enor-
mous new subjective forces emerged from colonization and reached
modernity, they recognized that
the primary task is not getting into
but getting out of modernity.
Toward a New Global Paradigm
A paradigm shift in the world economic and political order was
taking place. One important element ofthis passage was the fact
that the world market as a structure ofhierarchy and command
became more important and decisive in all the zones and regions
in which the old imperialisms had previously operated. The world
market began to appear as the centerpiece ofan apparatus that could
regulate global networks ofcirculation. This unification was still
posed only at a formal level. The processes that arose on the conflic-
tual terrain ofliberation struggles and expanding capitalist circulation
were not necessarily or immediately compatible with the new struc-
tures ofthe world market. Integration proceeded unevenly and at
252
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
different speeds. In different regions and often within the same
region, diverse forms of labor and production coexisted, as did also
different regimes of social reproduction. What might have seemed
like a coherent central axis ofthe restructuring ofglobal production
was shattered into a thousand particular fragments and the unifying
process was experienced everywhere singularly. Far from being
unidimensional, the process ofrestructuring and unifying command
over production was actually an explosion of innumerable different
productive systems. The processes ofthe unification ofthe world
market operated paradoxically through diversity and diversification,
but its tendency was nonetheless real.
Several important effects follow from the tendency toward
the unification ofthe world market. On the one hand, the wide
spread ofthe disciplinary model ofthe organization oflabor and
society outward from the dominant regions produced in the rest
of the world a strange effect of proximity, simultaneously pulling
it closer and isolating it away in a ghetto. That is, liberation struggles
found themselves ‘‘victorious’’ but nonetheless consigned to the
ghetto ofthe world market—a vast ghetto with indeterminate
borders, a shantytown, a favela. On the other hand, huge populations
underwent what might be called
wage emancipation
as a result of
these processes. Wage emancipation meant the entrance ofgreat
masses ofworkers into the disciplinary regime ofmodern capitalist
production, whether it be in the factory, the fields, or some other
site ofsocial production, and hence these populations were liberated
from the semi-servitude that imperialism had perpetuated. Entry
into the wage system can be bloody (and it has been); it can repro-
duce systems offerocious repression (and it has done so); but even
in the shacks ofthe new shantytowns and favelas, the wage relation
does determine the constitution ofnew needs, desires, and demands.
For example, the peasants who become wage workers and who are
subjected to the discipline ofthe new organization oflabor in many
cases suffer worse living conditions, and one cannot say that they
are more free than the traditional territorialized laborer, but they
do become infused with
a new desire for liberation.
When the new
D I S C I P L I N A R Y G O V E R N A B I L I T Y
253
disciplinary regime constructs the tendency toward a global market
oflabor power, it constructs also the possibility ofits antithesis. It
constructs the desire to escape the disciplinary regime and tenden-
tially an undisciplined multitude ofworkers who want to be free.
The increasing mobility oflarge portions ofthe global proletar-
iat is another important consequence ofthe tendential unification
ofthe world market. In contrast to the old imperialist regimes
in which the currents oflabor mobility were primarily regulated
vertically between colony and metropole, the world market opens
up wider horizontal paths. The constitution ofa global market
organized along a disciplinary model is traversed by tensions that
open mobility in every direction; it is a transversal mobility that is
rhizomatic rather than arborescent. Our interest here is not only
in giving a phenomenological description ofthe existing situation,
but also in recognizing the possibilities inherent in that situation.
The new transversal mobility ofdisciplined labor power is significant
because it indicates a real and powerful search for freedom and the
formation of new, nomadic desires that cannot be contained and
controlled within the disciplinary regime.22 It is true that many
workers across the world are subject to forced migrations in dire
circumstances that are hardly liberatory in themselves. It is true,
too, that this mobility rarely increases the cost oflabor power; in
fact, it most often decreases it, increasing instead the competition
among workers. The mobility does carry for capital a high price,
however, which is the increased desire for liberation.
Some significant macroeconomic effects follow from the new
mobility introduced by capital’s global disciplinary paradigm. The
mobility ofpopulations makes it increasingly difficult to manage
national markets (particularly national labor markets) individually.
The adequate domain for the application of capitalist command
is no longer delimited by national borders or by the traditional
international boundaries. Workers who flee the Third World to
go to the First for work or wealth contribute to undermining the
boundaries between the two worlds. The Third World does not
really disappear in the process ofunification ofthe world market
254
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
but enters into the First, establishes itselfat the heart as ghetto,
shantytown, favela, always again produced and reproduced. In turn,
the First World is transferred to the Third in the form of stock
exchanges and banks, transnational corporations and icy skyscrapers
ofmoney and command. Economic geography and political geogra-
phy both are destabilized in such a way that the boundaries among
the various zones are themselves fluid and mobile. As a result, the
entire world market tends to be the only coherent domain for the
effective application of capitalist management and command.
At this point the capitalist regimes have to undergo a process
ofreform and restructuring in order to ensure their capacity to
organize the world market. This tendency emerges clearly only in
the 1980s (and is established definitively after the collapse of the
Soviet model ofmodernization), but already at the moment ofits
first appearance its principal features are clearly defined. It has to
be a new mechanism ofthe general control ofthe global process
and thus a mechanism that can coordinate politically the new dy-
namics ofthe global domain ofcapital and the subjective dimensions
ofthe actors; it has to be able to articulate the imperial dimension
ofcommand and the transversal mobility ofthe subjects. We will
see in the next section how this process was realized historically,
and thus we will begin to address directly the processes ofthe
constitution ofa global apparatus ofgovernment.
Real Subsumption and the World Market
Before we move on, the expository development of our study
demands that we look more closely at the relationship between
this tendency toward the realization ofthe world market and the
paradigm ofdisciplinary production and government. How does
the spread ofdisciplinary regimes throughout the world represent
a fundamental genealogical moment of Empire? We can give one
explanation why this is the case by linking Marx’s description of
the phases ofthe capitalist subsumption ofsociety together with
his analyses ofthe tendency toward the world market. The two
movements actually coincide at a certain point, or really the capitalist
D I S C I P L I N A R Y G O V E R N A B I L I T Y
255
subsumption ofsociety tends to be completed in the construction
ofthe world market.
Earlier we saw that the practices ofimperialism involve capital’s
internalization ofits outside and are thus processes ofthe
formal
subsumption
oflabor under capital. Marx uses the term ‘ f
ormal
subsumption’’ to name processes whereby capital incorporates under
its own relations ofproduction laboring practices that originated
outside its domain.23 The processes offormal subsumption are thus
intrinsically related to the extension ofthe domain ofcapitalist
production and capitalist markets. At a certain point, as capitalist
expansion reaches its limit, the processes offormal subsumption
can no longer play the central role. The processes ofthe
real subsump-
tion
oflabor under capital do not rely on the outside and do not
involve the same processes ofexpansion. Through the real subsump-
tion, the integration oflabor into capital becomes more intensive
than extensive and society is ever more completely fashioned by
capital. There are certainly processes ofreal subsumption without
a world market, but there cannot be a fully realized world market
without the processes ofreal subsumption. In other words, the
realization ofthe world market and the general equalization or at
least management ofrates ofprofit on a world scale cannot be the
result simply offinancial or monetary factors but must come about
through a transformation of social and productive relations. Disci-
pline is the central mechanism ofthis transformation. When a new
social reality is formed, integrating both the development of capital
and the proletarianization ofthe population into a single process, the
political form ofcommand must itselfbe modified and articulated in
a manner and on a scale adequate to this process, a global quasi-
state ofthe disciplinary regime.
Marx’s intuitions ofthe processes ofreal subsumption do not