Authors: Professor Michael Hardt,Antonio Negri
Tags: #Philosophy, #Political, #Political Science, #General, #American Government
waged directly against capitalist command. The refusal of work and
the social unification ofthe proletariat came together in a frontal
attack against the coercive organization ofsocial labor and the
disciplinary structures ofcommand. This worker attack was com-
pletely political—even when many mass practices, particularly of
youth, seemed decidedly apolitical—insofar as it exposed and struck
the political nerve centers ofthe economic organization ofcapital.
The peasant and proletarian struggles in the subordinate coun-
tries also imposed reform on local and international political regimes.
Decades ofrevolutionary struggle—from the Chinese Revolution
to Vietnam and from the Cuban Revolution to the numerous
liberation struggles throughout Latin America, Africa, and the Arab
world—had pushed forward a proletarian wage demand that various
socialist and/or nationalist reformist regimes had to satisfy and that
directly destabilized the international economic system. The ideol-
ogy ofmodernization, even when it did not bring ‘‘development,’’
created new desires that exceeded the established relations ofpro-
duction and reproduction. The sudden increase in the costs ofraw
materials, energy, and certain agricultural commodities in the 1960s
and 1970s was a symptom ofthese new desires and the rising pressure
of the international proletariat on the wage. The effects of these
struggles not only were a quantitative matter but also determined
a qualitatively new element that profoundly marked the intensity
ofthe crisis. For more than one hundred years the practices of
imperialism had worked to subsume all forms of production
throughout the world under the command ofcapital, and that
tendency was only intensified in this period oftransition. The
tendency created necessarily a potential or virtual unity ofthe
international proletariat. This
virtual unity
was never fully actualized R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
263
as a
global political unity,
but it nonetheless had substantial effects.
In other words, the few instances of the actual and conscious interna-
tional organization oflabor are not what seem most important here,
but rather the
objective
coincidence ofstruggles that overlap precisely because, despite their radical diversity, they were all directed against
the international disciplinary regime ofcapital. The growing coinci-
dence determined what we call an accumulation ofstruggles.
This accumulation ofstruggles undermined the capitalist strat-
egy that had long relied on the hierarchies ofthe international
divisions oflabor to block any global unity among workers. Already
in the nineteenth century, before European imperialism had fully
bloomed, Engels was bemoaning the fact that the English proletariat
was put in the position ofa ‘‘labor aristocracy’’ because its interests
lay with the project ofBritish imperialism rather than with the
ranks ofcolonial labor power. In the period ofthe decline of
imperialisms, strong international divisions oflabor certainly re-
mained, but the imperialist advantages ofany national working class
had begun to wither away. The common struggles ofthe proletariat
in the subordinate countries took away the possibility ofthe old
imperialist strategy of transferring the crisis from the metropolitan
terrain to its subordinate territories. It was no longer feasible to rely
on Cecil Rhodes’s old strategy ofplacating the domestic dangers
ofclass struggle in Europe by shifting the economic pressures to
the still peaceful order of the dominated imperialist terrain main-
tained with brutally effective techniques. The proletariat formed
on the imperialist terrain was now itselforganized, armed, and
dangerous. There was thus a tendency toward the unity ofthe
international or multinational proletariat in one common attack
against the capitalist disciplinary regime.5 The resistance and initia-
tive ofthe proletariat in the subordinate countries resonated as a
symbol and model both above and within the proletariat ofthe
dominant capitalist countries. By virtue ofthis convergence, the
worker struggles throughout the domain ofinternational capital
already decreed the end ofthe division between First and Third
Worlds and the potential political integration ofthe entire global
264
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
proletariat. The convergence ofstruggles posed on an international
scale the problem oftransforming laboring cooperation into revolu-
tionary organization and actualizing the virtual political unity.
With this objective convergence and accumulation ofstrug-
gles, Third Worldist perspectives, which may earlier have had a
limited utility, were now completely useless. We understand Third
Worldism to be defined by the notion that the primary contradiction
and antagonism ofthe international capitalist system is between the
capital ofthe First World and the labor ofthe Third.6 The potential
for revolution thus resides squarely and exclusively in the Third
World. This view has been evoked implicitly and explicitly in a
variety ofdependency theories, theories ofunderdevelopment, and
world system perspectives.7 The limited merit ofthe Third Worldist
perspective was that it directly countered the ‘‘First Worldist’’ or
Eurocentric view that innovation and change have always origi-
nated, and can only originate, in Euro-America. Its specular opposi-
tion ofthis false claim, however, leads only to a position that is
equally false. We find this Third Worldist perspective inadequate
because it ignores the innovations and antagonisms oflabor in the
First and Second Worlds. Furthermore, and most important for our
argument here, the Third Worldist perspective is blind to the real
convergence ofstruggles across the world, in the dominant and
subordinate countries alike.
Capitalist Responseto theCrisis
As the global confluence ofstruggles undermined the capitalist and
imperialist capacities ofdiscipline, the economic order that had
dominated the globe for almost thirty years, the Golden Age of
U.S. hegemony and capitalist growth, began to unravel. The form
and substance ofthe capitalist management ofinternational develop-
ment for the postwar period were dictated at the conference at
Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in 1944.8 The Bretton Woods
system was based on three fundamental elements. Its first characteris-
tic was the comprehensive economic hegemony ofthe United
States over all the nonsocialist countries. This hegemony was secured
R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
265
through the strategic choice ofa liberal development based on
relatively free trade and moreover by maintaining gold (of which
the United States possessed about one third ofthe world total) as
the guarantee ofthe power ofthe dollar. The dollar was ‘‘as good
as gold.’’ Second, the system demanded the agreement for monetary
stabilization between the United States and the other dominant
capitalist countries (first Europe then Japan) over the traditional
territories ofEuropean imperialisms, which had been dominated
previously by the British pound and the French franc. Reform in
the dominant capitalist countries could thus be financed by a surplus
ofexports to the United States and guaranteed by the monetary
system ofthe dollar. Finally, Bretton Woods dictated the establish-
ment ofa quasi-imperialist relationship ofthe United States over
all the subordinate nonsocialist countries. Economic development
within the United States and stabilization and reform in Europe
and Japan were all guaranteed by the United States insofar as it
accumulated imperialist superprofits through its relationship to the
subordinate countries.
The system ofU.S. monetary hegemony was a fundamentally
new arrangement because, whereas the control ofprevious interna-
tional monetary systems (notably the British) had been firmly in
the hands ofprivate bankers and financiers, Bretton Woods gave
control to a series ofgovernmental and regulatory organizations,
including the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and
ultimately the U.S. Federal Reserve.9 Bretton Woods might thus
be understood as the monetary and financial face of the hegemony
ofthe New Deal model over the global capitalist economy.
The Keynesian and pseudo-imperialist mechanisms ofBretton
Woods eventually went into crisis when the continuity ofthe
workers’ struggles in the United States, Europe, and Japan raised
the costs ofstabilization and reformism, and when anti-imperialist
and anticapitalist struggles in subordinate countries began to under-
mine the extraction ofsuperprofits.10 When the imperialist motor
could no longer move forward and the workers’ struggles become
ever more demanding, the U.S. trade balance began to lean heavily
266
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
in the direction ofEurope and Japan. A first phase ofcrisis—creeping
rather than rampant—extended from the early to the late 1960s.
Since the controls provided by Bretton Woods made the dollar
de facto inconvertible, the monetary mediation of international
production and trade developed through a phase characterized by
the relatively free circulation ofcapital, the construction ofa strong
Eurodollar market, and the fixing ofpolitical parity more or less
everywhere in the dominant countries.11 The explosion of1968 in
Europe, the United States, and Japan, coupled with the Vietnamese
military victory over the United States, however, completely dis-
solved this provisory stabilization. Stagflation gave way to rampant
inflation. The second phase ofthe crisis might be thought ofas
beginning on August 17, 1971, when President Nixon decoupled
the dollar from the gold standard, making the dollar inconvertible
de jure and adding a 10 percent surcharge to all imports from
Europe to the United States.12 The entire U.S. debt was effectively
pushed onto Europe. This operation was accomplished only by
virtue ofthe economic and political power ofthe United States,
which thus reminded the Europeans ofthe initial terms ofthe
agreement, ofits hegemony as the highest point ofexploitation
and capitalist command.
In the 1970s the crisis became official and structural. The
system ofpolitical and economic equilibria invented at Bretton
Woods had been completely thrown into disarray, and what re-
mained was only the brute fact of U.S. hegemony. The declining
effectiveness of the Bretton Woods mechanisms and the decomposi-
tion ofthe monetary system ofFordism in the dominant countries
made it clear that the reconstruction ofan international system of
capital would have to involve a comprehensive restructuring of
economic relations and a paradigm shift in the definition of world
command. Such a crisis, however, is not always an entirely negative
or unwelcome event from the perspective of capital. Marx claims
that capital does indeed have a fundamental interest in economic
crisis for its transformative power. With respect to the overall system,
individual capitalists are conservative. They are focused primarily
R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
267
on maximizing their individual profits in the short term even when
this leads down a ruinous path for collective capital in the long term.
Economic crisis can overcome these resistances, destroy unprofitable
sectors, restructure the organization ofproduction, and renew its
technologies. In other words, economic crisis can push forward a
transformation that reestablishes a high general rate of profit, thus
responding effectively on the very terrain defined by the worker
attack. Capital’s general devaluation and its efforts to destroy worker
organization serve to transform the substance of the crisis—the
disequilibria ofcirculation and overproduction—into a reorganized
apparatus ofcommand that rearticulates the relationship between
development and exploitation.
Given the intensity and coherence ofthe struggles ofthe 1960s
and 1970s, two paths were open to capital for accomplishing the
tasks ofplacating the struggles and restructuring command, and it
tried each ofthem in turn. The first path, which had only a limited
effectiveness, was
the repressive option
—a fundamentally conservative operation. Capital’s repressive strategy was aimed at completely
reversing the social process, separating and disaggregating the labor
market, and reestablishing control over the entire cycle ofproduc-
tion. Capital thus privileged the organizations that represented a
guaranteed wage for a limited portion of the work force, fixing that
segment ofthe population within their structures and reinforcing the
separation between those workers and more marginalized popula-
tions. The reconstruction ofa system ofhierarchical compartmental-
ization, both within each nation and internationally, was accom-