Daily Life During the French Revolution (9 page)

 

 

REVOLUTION AND THE ECONOMY

 

Figures show that the total value of the country’s trade in
1795 was less than half what it had been in 1789; by 1815, it was still only 60
percent of what it had been at the beginning of the revolution.

More than any other class of people, perhaps, the
manufacturers felt the effects of the revolution the most profoundly. The
rivalry with English textile makers, strong in 1787 and 1788; the revolutionary
movement in 1789 in which so many landlords, clergy, and those in public
employment lost income; the emigration of the wealthy classes, causing
unemployment for many others; the falling value of the assignats—all combined
to lower purchasing power and industrial output. Those whose investments were
safe nevertheless restricted their buying and hoarded their money, apprehensive
about the unsettled state and the prospect of civil war. The result was,
predictably, immense unemployment and a starving population, especially in the
big cities.

On December 29, 1789, Young visited Lyon and conversed with
the citizens. Twenty thousand people were unemployed, badly fed by charity;
industry was in a dismal state; and the distress among the lower classes was
the worst they had ever experienced. The cause of the problem was attributed to
stagnation of trade resulting from the emigration of the rich. Bankruptcies
were common.

The Constituent Assembly’s economic reforms were guided by
laissez-faire doctrine, along with hostility to privileged corporations that
resembled too much those of the old regime. The Assembly wanted to make
opportunities accessible to every man and to promote individual initiative. It
dismantled internal tariffs, along with chartered trading monopolies, and
abolished the guilds of merchants and artisans. Every citizen was given the
right to enter any trade and to freely conduct business. Regulation of wages
would no longer be of government concern, nor would the quality of the product.
Workers, the Assembly insisted, must bargain in the economic marketplace as
individuals; it thereby banned associations and strikes. Similar precepts of
economic individualism applied to the countryside. Peasants and landlords were
free to cultivate their fields as they liked, regardless of traditional
collective practices. Communal traditions, however, were deep-seated and
resistant to change.

The Atlantic and Mediterranean port cities, all centers of
developing capitalist activity, had suffered from anti-federalist repression
and from English naval blockades. In textile towns such as Lille, the decline
was abrupt and ruinous. No matter what business they were in, tailors,
wigmakers, watchmakers—all those engaged in businesses related to deluxe items
or pursuits—lost their clientele. Even shoemakers suffered along with other
lower-class enterprises, except for the very few who managed to get contracts
to supply the military. In heavy industry such as iron and cannon manufacture,
some opportunities were provided by the continuing warfare, which tended to
focus capital and labor on the provision of armaments. For most businesses,
however, the situation appeared gloomy.

In 1790, while in Paris, Young learned that the cotton
mills in Normandy had stood still for nine months. Many spinning jennies had
been destroyed by the locals, who believed they were Satan’s invention and
would put them out of work. Trade, Young said, was in a deplorable condition.

All cities were in a sad state and remained so throughout
the revolutionary period. When Samuel Romilly returned to Bordeaux in 1802,
during a period of peace with England, he was grieved to see the silent docks
and the grass growing long between the flagstones of the quays. The sugar trade
with the West Indies continued to flourish, but in port cities connected to the
slave trade, people were alarmed over talk in the National Convention about
freeing the blacks, who provided the labor for the colonial sugar industry.

 

 

THE ASSIGNAT

 

Preceding the revolution, the basic money of account was
the livre, of which three made an écu, and 24 livres equaled one louis. The
livre was made up of 20 sous (the older term was sols), and the sous was
divided into 12 deniers. (The system was similar to that used in
England—pounds, shillings, and pence—until the 1970s.)

On December 19, 1789, to redeem the huge public debt and to
counterbalance the growing deficit, the revolutionary Constituent Assembly
issued treasury notes or bonds called assignats, to the amount of 400 million
livres distributed in 1,000-livre notes. These were intended as short-term
obligations pending the sale of confiscated lands formerly owned by the
nobility and the church and were distributed to creditors of the state to be
exchanged for land of equal value or redeemed at 5 percent interest. The
assignats were then to be liquidated, reducing government debt. Neither the
economy nor the royal tax revenues increased as quickly as the deputies had
hoped; assignats were made legal tender in April 1790, and subsequent issues
bore no interest.

In the autumn of 1790, the government issued another 400
million in assignats. In following years, more and more were issued in smaller
denominations of 50 livres, then 5 livres, and, finally, 10 sous. By January
1793, about 2.3 billion assignats were in circulation. The paper currency
rapidly became inflated, and people hoarded metallic coins that had been used
previously. By July 1793, a 100-livre note was only worth 23 livres.

The stringent financial measures put in place during the
Terror temporarily stabilized the value of the assignat at one-third of its
face value. However, by early 1796, under the Directory, inflation again
increased dramatically, and the assignats in circulation were worth less than 1
percent of their original value. This did not even cover the cost of printing
them. Severe inflation stopped only when all paper currency was recalled and
redeemed at the rate of 3,000 livres in assignats to one franc in gold. On May
21, 1797, all unredeemed assignats were declared void.

 

The value of the assignats depreciated rapidly. The
beggar symbolizes the subsequent ruin of thousands of investors.

 

 

TAXATION

 

The company Farmers-General purchased the privilege of
collecting taxes and paying state debts for the various government departments.
Taxes thus passed through private hands, and some of it wound up in private
pockets. There was no central bank to provide economic stability, only a group
of businessmen who sought to find the best balance between a functioning government
and their own profits. The tax farmer advanced a specified sum of money to the
royal treasury and then collected a like sum in taxes. Given exceptional powers
to collect the money, tax farmers bore arms, conducted searches, and imprisoned
uncooperative citizens. The money collected over and above that specified in
the contract with the government went to the tax farm. Tax farmers were usually
rich men and hated by the general public.

There were various kinds of taxes levied in different parts
of the country. The taille was a direct tax collected on property and goods;
the clergy and the nobility were exempt from this levy, and the peasants bore
the brunt. Indirect taxes included the
gabelle
, or salt tax, a duty on
tobacco, the aides, which were excise duties collected on the manufacture,
sale, and consumption of a commodity, and the traites, customs duties collected
internally. There was no uniformity, and some sections of the country bore
heavier tax burdens than others. The main direct tax, the taille, was levied by
the crown on total income in the northern provinces but only on income from
landed property in the south.

 

 

SALT TAX

 

The government monopoly on salt went back as far as the
thirteenth century; the salt was extracted from seawater ponds that were left
to dry out. The detested salt tax (
gabelle
) had become a leading source
of royal income and was levied at different rates in various parts of the
country. In some regions, everyone over eight years of age was required to
purchase seven kilos of salt each year at a fixed government price. In other
regions, people were required to purchase a fixed quantity of salt per
household. There were other areas where the salt tax did not apply (
pays
exempt
), such as the Basque country and Brittany. Fortunes were made in the
illegal transport of salt.

The collectors and enforcers of the salt tax were often
crude, abusive men who were allowed to carry arms and to stop and search
whomever they pleased. They were not above looking for contraband by squeezing
the choicest parts of women who had no recourse but to suffer the humiliation.
Women sometimes did hide bags of salt in corsets and other places where they
hoped not to be squeezed; some concealed it in false rears of their dresses.
Salt rebellions were frequent, and battles sometimes erupted between smugglers
and tax collectors.

The Loire River was notorious for the movement of
contraband, since it separated tax-free Brittany from heavily taxed Anjou; the
price for salt was 591 sous per minot (49 kilos) in Anjou but 31 sous in
Brittany, which was exempt from the tax thanks to an agreement reached with the
crown when Brittany became part of France. The large number of families working
the salt ponds there were in the best position to ferry the salt across the
river, so the government passed a no-fishing-at-night law to curb the illegal
trade and stationed troops along the banks of the river in an attempt to end
the smuggling. The
gabelle
was abolished by the revolution but was
reinstated 15 years later; it continued in force until 1945.

 

 

3 - TRAVEL

 

At
the end of the Seven Years War, swarms of English people visited France, and
some left accounts of their travels there. Later, hostilities between France
and England during the American War of Independence nearly dried up the flow of
English tourists to Paris and the provinces, but it still did not stop
entirely, and the return to peace in 1783 brought another influx of Britons to
French shores.

Travelers to France, especially those from England, were
always surprised by the great distances and the plethora of internal customs
houses. Further, they found that there was no national language either spoken
or understood by a great many of the illiterate inhabitants and no uniform
system of administration, laws, taxes, weights and measures.

Although French people did not seem to travel much within
their own country, those who did, with interests different from those of
foreign visitors, have also left accounts that help portray the daily life of
the time. About half of the members of the Convention were sent out on
assignments to the departments (administrative districts) or to the army, and
some reports of their missions are available. For many, such as a
representative from Paris, a journey to the south was like going to a foreign
land.

 

 

MODES OF TRANSPORT

 

Major rivers in France, such as the Seine, Loire, Saône,
Rhône, and Garonne, had long been used as a means of transportation. To
supplement the river system and move cargo, some important canals were built in
the seventeenth century, including the Brienne, Orléans, and Languedoc. The Canal
du Midi, running from Toulouse to Béziers, made it possible to link the
Atlantic Ocean with the Mediterranean through southwest France. One could
travel on riverboats pulled by horses along the banks that in Paris embarked
from the Palais Royal or the bridge of Saint Paul. Arrangements for private
travel on commercial barges or riverboats over long distances seemed not to
appeal to many who, for whatever reason, preferred to go by horse and carriage.
For this manner of travel, the transportation system was in place, with
scheduled stops and prices. One could, for example, go to the Royal General
Bureau of Coaches and Freight and book a trip to anywhere in the realm.

By the late eighteenth century, the region of the Ile de
France had the best-constructed roads in Europe, greatly admired by foreigners.
However, when traveling by horse drawn vehicles over large distances, travelers
found that the roads sometimes became just bumpy tracks and that the journey
was slow and tedious. Going to Bordeaux or Strasbourg from Paris took six days;
traveling to Toulouse took seven or eight days, and to Marseille, nine days.

Other books

The Admissions by Meg Mitchell Moore
Up In A Heaval by Anthony, Piers
Ecstasy Wears Emeralds by Renee Bernard
The Fading by Christopher Ransom
A Taste of the Nightlife by Sarah Zettel
Grounds for Appeal by Bernard Knight


readsbookonline.com Copyright 2016 - 2024