The Baseball Economist: The Real Game Exposed (47 page)

70.
The Bill James Baseball Abstract,
1987.
71. The nature of the data used to estimate the regression results creates some complicated problems. For those readers who are familiar with some advanced regression techniques: I estimated the model using random effects and corrected for first-order serial correlation. I used the pitcher’s team’s seasonal BABIP for all pitchers to proxy defense, assumed the impact of age on ERA to be U-shaped (quadratic), and used indicator variables equal to 1 or 0 to identify the league and year in which the pitcher’s stats were posted. I made a correction for the propensity of a pitcher’s home park to yield runs. So pitchers with an unfriendly home park (such as Coors Field in Denver) are not punished, and pitchers with friendly home parks are not rewarded. See my study article in
Journal of Sports Economics,
“Does the Baseball Labor Market Properly Value Pitchers?” (forthcoming). Also, you can find some similar findings in my article “Another Look At DIPS” in
The Hardball Times
, May 24, 2005.
72. For the remainder of the analysis I exclude hit batters, because they are such rare events that don’t strongly correlate from year to year.
73. Michael Lewis,
Moneyball,
p. 236.
74.
Principles of Economics
, p. 43.
75. “Pay and Performance in Major League Baseball,”
American Economic Review
, 1974.
76. The relationship between winning and revenue is a quadratic function, with increasing dollar value added for each win beyond seventy-one.
77. Total Revenue = (0.126 × Run Difference) + (0.000665 × Run Difference
2
) + (3.88 × MSA Population) + 109.022; Adj. R
2
= .52. All estimates are statistically significant at the 5 percent level. I use the 2004 season to estimate the impact of the run differential on revenue as reported in the 2005
Forbes Business of Baseball
report. Estimates using several seasons of data did not yield much different results. The model is simple, but more complicated specifications—including the interaction between wins and population and per capita income—performed no better. While other factors may have some slight importance, they should not bias the relationship between wins and revenue.
78. Runs Scored = (3012.54 × OBP) + (1688.17 × SLG) + (29.18 × AL) −966.04; Adj. R
2
= .93. All estimates are statistically significant at the 5 percent level.
79. Runs Allowed = (−25.83 × K9) + (60.65 × BB9) + (249.5 × HR9) − (4196.21 × Team Outs on Balls in Play percent) + (26.64 × AL) + 3419.59; Adj. R
2
= .91. All estimates are statistically significant at the 5 percent level. Reported estimates in this edition include a correction, and therefore differ slightly from estimates reported in the first edition.
80.
The Fielding Bible
by John Dewan presents an experimental new system for objectively evaluating defense. Dewan estimates that Perez made twenty more plays than the average shortstop in 2005, which translates to about 9.2 runs. Using our runs-to-dollars conversion, this translates to approximately $1.22 million, which is close to the amount Cedeno would have added with his bat, $1.85 million.
81. Berri, Schmidt, and Brook,
The Wages of Wins,
p. 189.
82. Helyar,
Lords of the Realm: The Real History of Baseball
.
83. All price data from
www.teammarketing.com
. Rodney Fort compiles the many years of this data on his Web site (
www.rodneyfort.com/SportsData/BizFrame.htm
).
84.
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
, Oxford University Press, 1976, pp. 26–27.
85. Figure 22 graphically demonstrates exactly how price discrimination eliminates deadweight loss. A single-price monopolist maximizes its profits by producing the output where the additional revenue of selling an additional unit—known as marginal revenue (MR)—equals the cost of producing an additional unit— known at the marginal cost (MC). Thus, the monopolist in this example produces Q
m
amount of output, while it sells each unit for the price of P
m
. The rectangle A measures the profits captured by the monopolist. Triangles B and C represent two untapped profit opportunities to the monopolist.
From zero to Q
m,
every consumers pays price P
m,
although according to the demand curve (D), which captures the consumer willingness-to-pay for the product at different prices, some consumers are willing to pay more and less. Triangle B represents that revenue lost to a seller charging P
m,
because some consumers would be willing to pay a higher price. Qm to Q* is the quantity of the product that consumers would be willing to purchase if the price were less than Pm and greater than P*. To the left of Q* the price that would be received by the seller exceeds the marginal cost of producing those units. If the monopolist could sell the goods to these customers at a price lower than P
m,
it would do so because the additional revenue would exceed the additional cost. Triangle C represents the uncaptured revenue from units the monopolist doesn’t sell. This area is equal to the deadweight loss.
Together, the areas of Triangle B and C equal the total uncaptured revenue available to the monopolist if it could charge different prices to different consumers using price discrimination. Triangle B differs from C because B represents revenue lost from individuals who consume the product. We are not concerned with these individuals, because they valued these units at least as much as the amount they paid for them. The loss of revenue in Triangle C is much worse than the loss reflected in Triangle B, because the lost revenue of Triangle C also means that some sellable products will not be sold.
86. Ticket price data from
www.teammarketing.com
.
87.
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy,
p. 99.
88. Anyone interested in doing serious research with multiple regression analysis would be wise to acquire software that is designed to handle some common problems the empirical researcher faces. I typically use the regression package Stata, but R, SPSS, Limdep, and SAS all work well.
89. This assumes the data are distributed in a certain manner. Different regression estimators are needed for different types of data to interpret the statistical significance of coefficient estimates.
Bibliography
Albert, James, and Jay Bennett.
Curve Ball: Baseball, Statistics, and the Role of Chance in the Game
. New York: Copernicus, 2001.
Barro, Robert.
Getting It Right: Market Choices in a Free Society
. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996.
Bastiat, Frédéric. “That Which Is Seen, and That Which Is Not Seen,” 1850.
Berri, David J., Martin B. Schmidt, and Stacey L. Brook. The Wages of Wins. Stanford: Stanford University Press. 2006.
Bradbury, John Charles. “Another Look at DIPS.”
The Hardball Times
, May 24, 2005. Bradbury, John Charles. “Does the Baseball Labor Market Properly Value Pitchers?”
Journal of Sports Economics
, forthcoming.
Bradbury, John Charles. “The Mazzone Effect Revisited.”
The Baseball Analysts
, March 17, 2005. (http://baseballanalysts.com/archives/2005/03/the_mazzone_eff1.php).
Bradbury, John Charles. “Moneyball and Efficient Efficiency.”
The Hardball Times
, July 26, 2005.
Bradbury, John Charles. “Quantifying the Market Size Advantage in MLB.”
The Hardball Times
, March 27, 2004.
Bradbury, John Charles, and Douglas J. Drinen. “Crime and Punishment in Major League Baseball: The Case of the Designated Hitter and Hit Batters,”
Economic Inquiry
, forthcoming.
Bradbury, John Charles, and Douglas J. Drinen. “The Designated Hitter, Moral Hazard, and Hit Batters: New Evidence from Game-Level Data,”
Journal of Sports Economics
, August 2006.
Bradbury, John Charles, and Douglas J. Drinen. “Pigou at the Plate: Externalities in Major League Baseball,”
Journal of Sports Economics,
(forthcoming).
Carlyle, Thomas. “Occasional Discourse on the Negro Question.”
Fraser’s Magazine for Town and Country
, December 1849, Vol. 40: 670–679.
Canseco, Jose.
Juiced: Wild Times, Rampant ’Roids, Smash Hits, and How Baseball Got Big.
New York: Regan Books, 2005.
De Vany, Arthur. “Steroids, Home Runs and the Law of Genius.”
Economic Inquiry
, forthcoming.
Dewan, John.
The Fielding Bible
. Skokie, IL: ACTA Sports, 2006.
Fainaru-Wada, Mark, and Lance Williams.
Game of Shadows: Barry Bonds, BALCO, and the Steroids Scandal that Rocked Professional Sports.
New York: Gotham, 2006.
Goff, Brian L., William F. Shughart, and Robert D. Tolison. “Batter Up! Moral Hazard and the Effects of the Designated Hitter Rule on Hit Batsmen.”
Economic Inquiry
, 1997, Vol. 35: 16–26.
Goff, Brian L., William F. Shughart, and Robert D. Tolison. “Moral Hazard and the Effects of the Designated Hitter Rule Revisited.”
Economic Inquiry
, 1998, Vol. 36: 688–692.
Gould, Stephen Jay.
Full House: The Spread of Excellence from Plato to Darwin
. New York: Three Rivers Press, 1996.
Hakes, Jahn K., and Raymond D. Sauer. “An Economic Evaluation of the Moneyball Hypothesis,”
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, 2006, Vol. 20: 178–185.
Helyar, John.
Lords of the Realm: The Real History of Baseball.
New York: Balantine Books, 1995.
James, Bill.
The New Bill James Historical Abstract
. New York: Free Press, 2003.
James, Bill, and Rob Neyer.
The Neyer
/
James Guide to Pitching
, New York: Fireside, 2004.
Kawaura, Akihiko, and Sumner La Croix. “Baseball in Japan and North America: Same Game, Same Rules, Same Results?” Manuscript, University of Hawaii. 2002.
Landsburg, Steven.
The Armchair Economist: Economics and Everyday Life
. New York: The Free Press, 1993.
Levitt, Steven D. “The Hazards of Moral Hazard.”
Economic Inquiry
, 1998, Vol. 36: 685–687.
Levitt, Steven D., and Stephen Dubner.
Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything
, New York: William Morrow, 2005.
Levy, David M.
How the Dismal Science Got Its Name: Classical Economics and the Ur-Text of Racial Politics
. The University of Michigan Press, 2001.
Lindsey, George. “An Investigation of Strategies in Baseball.”
Operations Research,
1963, Vol. 11: 447–501.
Marshal, Alfred.
Principles of Economics
. Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books, 1997.
Mazzone, Leo, and Scott Freeman.
Leo Mazzone’s Tales from the Braves Mound.
Champaign, IL: Sports Publishing, L.L.C., 2003.
Merron, Jeff. “Rock of Atlanta.”
ESPN.com
E-Ticket
, September 17–18, 2005.
Posnanski, Joe. “Bill James Finally Gets Enough of Royals.”
Kansas City Star,
November 10, 2002.
Quirk, James, and Rodney Fort.
Pay Dirt: The Business of Professional Team Sports.
Princeton University Press, 1992.
Ritter, Lawrence S. The Glory of Their Times: The Story of the Early Days of Baseball Told
By the Men Who Played It
. New York: Vintage, 1985.
Rosenthal, Ken. “Mets Get Shot with Mighty Clemens at the Bat.”
The Sporting News,
June 13, 2002.
Schell, Michael J.
Baseball’s All-Time Best Sluggers: Adjusted Batting Performance from Strikeouts to Home Runs
. Princeton University Press, 2005.
Schmidt, Martin B., and David J. Berri. “On the Evolution of Competitive Balance: The Impact of Increasing Global Search.”
Economic Inquiry
, October 2003.
Schumpeter, Joseph A.
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy
. New York: Harper, 1950.
Schwarz, Alan.
The Numbers Game: Baseball’s Lifelong Fascination with Statistics
. New York: Thomas Dunne Books, 2004.
Scully, Gerald. “Pay and Performance in Major League Baseball.”
American EconomicReview
, Vol. 65: 915–930.
Stigler, George J.
The Economist as Preacher and Other Essays
. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1982.
Thorn, John, and Pete Palmer.
The Hidden Game of Baseball: A Revolutionary Approachto Baseball and Statistics
. New York: Dolphin, 1984.
Trandel, Gregory A., Lawrence H. White, and Peter G. Klein. “The Effect of the Designated Hitter Rule on Hit Batsmen: Pitcher’s Moral Hazard or the Team’s Cost-Benefit Calculation.”
Economic Inquiry
, 1998, Vol. 36: 679–684.
Tullock, Gordon. “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft.”
Western Economic Journal,
1967, Vol. 5: 224–232.

Other books

Cold Light by John Harvey
Justicia uniforme by Donna Leon
The Tiger Queens by Stephanie Thornton
Night Rounds by Helene Tursten
Serpents Rising by David A. Poulsen
It's Nobody's Fault by Harold Koplewicz
Bite by Jenny Lyn


readsbookonline.com Copyright 2016 - 2024